ADVERTISEMENT

Why a Mansion Tax Could Be a Conservative Winner

Why a Mansion Tax Could Be a Conservative Winner

(Bloomberg Opinion) -- Amid preparations for the U.K.’s first post-Brexit budget, there have been reports that the Conservative Party is considering an idea that many in Boris Johnson’s party regard as most un-Conservative: a so-called mansion tax. The reaction in the conservative press has been one of surprise and outrage, and it could well have been one of the issues of friction which led to Sajid Javid leaving the government. Indeed, the Sunday Telegraph newspaper reported at the weekend that Prime Minister Johnson had shelved the plan.

Yet the tax is hardly the attack on home ownership, or the wealthy, that it’s often portrayed to be. I might be expected to say that, since I proposed the idea at the 2010 general election and then repeatedly as business secretary in the subsequent coalition government. Perhaps its time has finally come.

Ignoring the emotive label, a “mansion” tax is essentially an adaptation of Britain’s current system of property taxes, known as council tax, which are levied to finance local government. The existing system is regressive, not merely in terms of income but in terms of wealth; that is, occupiers of more valuable properties pay a smaller proportion of the value of their asset than those whose homes are less valuable.

In other countries, property taxes are usually proportional to the value of homes and in some cases progressive. Ireland, for example, charges 0.18% of value annually up to 1 million euros ($1.08 million) and 0.25% on any excess. Such international comparisons are difficult to make, but one estimate by the Tax Foundation ranks the U.K. as having the highest property taxes in Europe, averaging 2.5% of the private capital stock (a reasonable proxy for property value), with only France and Poland close, while Switzerland has negligible property tax at 0.1% and Germany not much more at 0.3%. The lesson is that property taxes don’t need to be high to be progressive.

In the U.S., property taxes vary considerably from state to state and within states. On a somewhat different but comparable measure — average tax in relation to the value of property — rates vary from 0.2% in Louisiana to 1.9% in New Jersey and 1.8% in Texas. In upstate New York some counties levy much higher rates. There is, however, some offset in the U.S. for those people who have large mortgages, through tax relief on interest. 

The British council tax was introduced with little regard for international comparisons or progressive values. Conservative Prime Minister John Major brought it in almost 30 years ago to replace Margaret Thatcher’s hated poll tax (a fixed charge per head, regardless of income or asset wealth, widely credited with precipitating her downfall).

Council tax was drawn up based on 1991 property values and such is the political sensitivity of the tax that no government has dared to revalue the properties despite enormous changes in house prices since then. Resistance to higher levels of council tax led to freezes during the coalition government (2010-2015) in which my party, the Liberal Democrats, governed with David Cameron’s Conservatives. An effective cap on increases of 3% per year now operates, leaving cash-strapped councils little room to raise additional money.

One major source of unfairness within an already unpopular tax is the eight bands — designated by the letters A to H — used to establish property value. Band D is 50% higher than Band A, and Band H, for properties worth 320,000 pounds in 1991 prices ($415,360 at current exchange rates), is twice as high as Band D. And there are no bands above Band H. The regressive overall effect is compounded by the fact that councils in the most valuable parts of Britain, and especially parts of London, levy low rates of council tax.

Proposals to make the structure more progressive by adding a series of additional bands were seen as an attack on “aspiration” and criticized as causing hardship for the asset rich, but income poor, elderly. The first reflects a particularly British concept of wealth creation through housing inflation rather than through innovation and investment. And while there are options available for the mainly elderly residents affected by a more progressive tax (from downsizing to smaller property or acquiring financial products that release equity),  older property owners in Britain, as elsewhere, are a politically powerful group that resists change.

The coalition came close to adopting council tax reform, as part of a compromise package between then Chancellor George Osborne and my Lib Dem colleagues: trading the mansion tax we wanted for the lower rates of income tax on high earners that the Tories wanted. But at the last moment, Cameron vetoed it, tinkering instead with thresholds and the upper rate of tax. He also increased charges on housing transactions, known as stamp duty, which had the perverse effect of inhibiting sales of property and mobility.

Boris Johnson, then Mayor of London, captured the politics of it in a column he wrote for the Mail at the time, calling “Cable’s Mansion Tax” a “brutally unfair attack on EVERY homeowner.”

The appeal of a tax on higher end properties — perhaps of 1% annually on properties worth more than 2 million pounds ($2.61 million) — for a politically secure Conservative Party is obvious. For a government that has sworn off income tax increases, it could raise much-needed revenue (we estimated about 2 billion pounds a year during the coalition period) to fund a major expenditure program. It would send a powerful signal of support to depressed provincial towns that don’t have much high-value property to tax, and the revenue from the better off south of the country could then be recycled to these less advantaged areas. If a percentage rate tax is too much to contemplate, simply adding four bands to the existing Council Tax at the top end could have a similar effect, though the revenue would not automatically go to the Treasury.

Either way, this is a tax that cannot be avoided; wealthy residents can’t take their mansions to the Virgin Islands or Switzerland. And, unlike taxes on income, employment and profits, taxing property values doesn’t discourage work or investment (taxing the underlying value of land would be even better, but that’s a bigger story).

Cynics would say that the Conservative Party’s donors have paid good money to ensure that such inconveniences don’t happen. But if the idea resurfaces, it would suggest that the Tories were embarked on a genuine attempt to redefine themselves as an inclusive and classless party with a new constituency among the relatively deprived.

To contact the editor responsible for this story: Therese Raphael at traphael4@bloomberg.net

This column does not necessarily reflect the opinion of Bloomberg LP and its owners.

Vince Cable is a former U.K. secretary of state for business and was leader of the Liberal Democrats from 2017 to 2019. He was previously chief economist at Royal Dutch Shell. He is currently a visiting professor at the London School of Economics. His next book, "Politicians and the Politics of Economics," will be published later this year.

©2020 Bloomberg L.P.